Monday, June 28, 2010

Giant Shoulders and the Theory of Storage

There is a saying about the pursuit of knowledge: “we are like dwarfs on the shoulders of giants.”[1] Such truism certainly applies to commodity pricing theory which includes: (1) the insurance aspect of commodity futures contracts emphasizing the role of the speculator; (2) the theory of storage, which is focused on the behavior of the inventory holder and commercial hedger; (3) the net-hedging-pressure hypothesis, which encompasses the behavior of both classes of participant; (4) the statistical behavior of commodity futures prices; (5) the attempt to reconcile commodity futures returns with the CAPM; (6) the role of commodities in a strategic asset allocation; and (7) the importance of yields as a long-term driver of commodity returns.[2] This article investigates the “theory of storage”[3] starting with the ideas of Holbrook Working.

It should be obvious that holders of commodities incur a storage cost for financing and storing inventories, including warehousing, handling charges and insurance. The conundrum is that not infrequently prices of the deferred futures are below that of the nearby future and/or spot price. When such situation occurs the market is said to reflect “inverse carrying charge” or “backwardation.” Much academic study has been dedicated to this seemingly strange phenomenon, and in providing a satisfactory answer as to why such conditions exist.

Working, whose 1949 paper The Theory of Price of Storage evolved from Keynes’ writings on commodity pricing, investigates the “theoretical problem… that it is existing supply rather than expected change in the supply which is involved in determining inter-temporal price relations.” This statement is more interesting if one goes back to Working’s 1948 article, Theory of the Inverse Carrying Charge in Futures Markets, in which he discusses “four different lines of attempt to explain inverse carrying charges.”
There seems to be substantial agreement among writers on futures markets that positive carrying charges tend to reflect marginal net costs of storage, and that when carrying charges are positive, prices of near and distant futures must respond about equally to any causes of price change. With regard to inverse carrying charges there is more difference of opinion and much reason for the student of futures markets to be dissatisfied with the present state of theory. How shall one explain a large inverse carrying charge between December and May in a United States wheat market? Do inverse carrying charges reliably forecast price declines? When prices of deferred futures fall below the spot price, does the futures market tend to lose effective connection with the cash market? These are some specific questions that call for answer and to which no satisfactory reply seems to be offered by prevailing theory.
Theory of the Inverse Carrying Charge - Working

The first explanation that Working (1948) explores is the idea that “cash and futures prices, though related, are not equivalents aside from the time element.” In the narrow sense the basis difference may be due to quality differentials or delivery locations.[4] However, as Working noted even back in the 1940s, the cash market is “clearly subsidiary from the standpoint of price formation” and that cash buyers and sellers ordinarily “bargain in terms of cents ‘over’ and cents ‘under’.” More broadly, it can be argued that “cash and futures prices may differ because they reflect the opinions of substantially different groups of traders.” However, this implies that cash-futures arbitrage is ineffective. In this regard Working points out that hedging is essentially a form of arbitrage, and notes that hedging persists even when markets are backwardated.

Next, Working addresses the view that futures prices tend to have a downward bias due to risk aversion. Keynes’ (1930) posits that producers are willing remunerate speculators in order “to avoid the risk of price fluctuations… during the period of production” causing the spot price to exceed the forward price. Vance (1946) adds “that future events always bear some degree of uncertainty is perhaps sufficient to justify a discounting of expectations.” Working admits that such ideas probably have some validity, but points out that risk avoidance can be applied to “possible future events” which are “price-elevating” as well as “price-depressing.” Rather, risk aversion is “pertinent as partial explanation of the ‘supply curve for storage’.”

The third point that Working disparages is “the belief that price differences between futures commonly reflect expectations regarding future developments.” Working argues that there is a continuity between nearby futures and deferred futures to the extent that “expectations arising from an existing supply situation” have a bearing on “expectations regarding future supply or demand developments” and vice-versa. This hypothesis is substantiated by empirical research in which evidence of “large changes in supply prospect on price relations” between nearby and distant futures contracts “lasted for not more than a week or two”, and was “followed quickly by a return toward the previous price relation” prior to the disturbance.

Working’s conclusion is that inverse carrying charges are best “explained in terms of the concept of price of storage.” First, “spot and futures prices for a commodity are intimately connected at all times” and “do not, in general, measure expected consequences of future developments.” Second, “inverse carrying charges are reliable indications of current shortage; the forecast of price decline which [the term structure implies] is no more reliable than a forecast… of the current supply situation itself.” Third, inverse carry is explained within a commercial context whereby hedgers “are willing to risk loss on a fraction of the stocks for the sake of assurance against having their… activities handicapped by shortage of supplies.”

From these thoughts Working (1949) developed his price-of-storage theory which “exposes clearly the fact that in the presence of hedging much storage does occur in response to a recorded, and competitively determined, assurance of return specifically for the storage itself.” In other words, the futures market “coupled with the practice of hedging, gives potential holders of [a commodity] a precise or at least a good approximate index of the return to be expected from storing [such commodity]. A known return for storage is, in essentials, a price of storage… determined in a free market through the competition of those who seek to supply storage service.”

With respect to inverse carrying charges, Working noted that “the problem [with the theory] tends to emerge clearly only when the price for deferred delivery is below the ‘nearer’ price.” Nevertheless, Working argues that such conditions can be rationalized by Kaldor’s (1939) ‘convenience yield’ whereby “stocks of all goods posses a yield… which is a compensation to the holder of stocks, [and] must be deducted from carrying costs proper in calculating net carrying cost.” In other words, to remain long in business a merchant “must carry stocks beyond known immediate needs and take his return in general customer satisfaction.” Thus “convenience yield may offset what appears as a fairly large loss from exercise of the storage function itself.”[5]

In effect, the price-of-storage theory, in which “positive carrying charges tend to reflect marginal net costs of storage,” can be extended to include negative carrying charges. According to Working (1948, 1949), “the supply-curve relationship between amount of storage and price of storage does not break down when the ‘price’ becomes negative… [which] occur when supplies are relatively scarce.” Rather, “a negative price of storage makes available for consumption in a year of shortage, supplies which would otherwise remain tied up in ‘convenience stocks’.” On the other hand, “if stocks to be stored are exceptionally large, the return for carrying [commodities] may exceed the ‘cost’ of storage… If stocks are quite moderate, competition among firms with storage facilities tends to result in the storage being provided for a rather small return.”

Michael Brennan in his 1958 paper, The Supply of Storage, both clarifies and expands on Working’s (1949) theory through description, formulae and empirical analysis. First he introduces the ‘demand for storage’ equation, Pt+1Pt = ft+1(St + Xt+1St+1) – ft(St-1 + Xt+1St),[6] wherein “the demand curve for storage of a commodity from period t to period t+1 will shift upward (e.g., to D΄D΄ in Figure 1) as result of an increase in production in t,… [and] opposite movements of [this variable] will produce a shift downward.” Brennan then defines the ‘net marginal cost of storage’ in period t as “marginal outlay on physical storage plus a marginal risk-aversion factor minus the marginal convenience yield on stocks.” He also assumes that “marginal outlay is approximately constant until total warehouse capacity is almost fully utilized”, and beyond this, outlay rises at an increasing rate. The net marginal cost of storage equation is mt΄(St) = ot΄(St) + rt΄(St) – ct΄(St).[7]

From such equations Brennan (1958) derives two graphics which elegantly reveal the key dynamics influencing the determination of positive versus negative carry prices. In the first graphic below, DD, D΄D΄ and D΄΄D΄΄ are demand-for-storage curves, and CC is the supply curve for storage. It is noted that the horizontal axis represents supply of storage at end of t, and the vertical axis represents the basis between deferred and nearby futures.


The second graphic reveals the interplay between convenience yield, storage outlay and risk aversion upon the net marginal cost of storage. Importantly, Brennan notes that risk aversion should be an increasing function of inventories held. “If a comparatively small quantity of stocks is held, the risk involved in undertaking the investment in stocks is also small.” However, “there is probably some critical level of stocks at which the loss would seriously endanger the firm’s credit position, and as stocks increase up to this point the risk incurred in holding them will steadily increase also—the risk of loss will constitute a part of the cost of storage.”

Brennan also adds to Kaldor’s and Working’s discussion on the convenience yield by noting it is “attributed to the advantage (in terms of less delay and lower costs) of being able to keep regular customers satisfied or of being able to take advantage of a rise in demand and price without resorting to a revision of the production schedule. Similarly, for a processing firm the availability of stocks as raw materials permits variations in production without incurring the trouble, cost and perhaps delays of frequent spot purchases and deliveries. A wholesaler can vary his sales in response to an increased flow of orders only if he has sufficient stocks on hand. The smaller the level of stocks on hand the greater will be the convenience yield of an additional unit.” Alternatively, “it is assumed that there is some quantity of stocks so large that the marginal convenience yield is zero.” Further, distinction is sometimes made between ‘surplus’ stocks, which Brennan notes are distinguished by a speculative motive, versus ‘pipeline’ or ‘working’ stocks.

To wrap up this article, we leave the reader with Lester Telser’s insights. Telser (1958) analyzed storage in relation to firms’ stockholding schedule, and then related the results of his study to conventionally-held ideas about commodity pricing which emphasizes the role of the speculator and the role of commodity futures contracts as insurance. In certain respects Telser’s findings support Working’s (1949) conclusion that “only some direct explanation of the price relation in terms of an existing condition can account for the fact that expectations regarding future events, which are directly pertinent to a distant forward price, have approximately the same effect on spot and near forward prices as on a distant forward price.”
A widely accepted theory advanced by Keynes and Hicks which relates the futures price and the expected spot price regards hedgers as buyers of insurance and speculators as sellers of insurance who must be induced to bear the risk of price changes. When statistical evidence was examined to see whether futures prices display an upward trend as they approach maturity predicted by this theory, it was found instead that futures prices display no trend. Although hedgers may be willing to pay speculators to bear the risks of price changes, they need not do so if speculators are eager to speculate. Firms that hedge can reduce their price risks at little or no cost to themselves. I accept the hypothesis that the futures price equals the expected spot price.
The forgoing was presented to help educate readers on the “theory of storage”, specifically key concepts in the ever-evolving debate of what factors most influence commodity prices. The conclusion we arrive at as a result of this exercise is the same conclusion we have deduced in other studies—pricing models are first and foremost informed by perspective, and perspective is informed by assumptions. As a result, the legacy of research will always remain inconclusive with respect to modeling the sources of returns in the commodity futures markets largely because these models have inherent shortcomings in being able to pinpoint an authoritative source of structural risk premium within the complexity of such markets.

Footnotes:
[1] “Dwarfs standing on the shoulders of giants” (Latin: nanos gigantium humeris insidentes) is a Western metaphor meaning, one who develops intellectual works by understanding the research created by notable thinkers of the past. The saying is attributed to Bernard of Chartres due to John of Salisbury’s reference in Metalogicon (1159).

[2] Hilary Till (2007). “Part I of A Long-Term Perspective on Commodity Futures Returns: Review of the Historical Literature” Intelligent Commodity Investing, Till and Eagleeye, Ed., London: Risk Books, p 39.

[3] In the paper, The Supply of Storage, Brennan (1958) clarifies that “supply of storage refers not to the supply of storage space but to the supply of commodities as inventories. In general, a supplier of storage is anyone who holds title to stocks with a view to their future sale, either in their present or in a modified form.”

[4] In the context of financial futures, “basis” is defined as spot price minus the futures price. There is a different basis for each delivery month for each contract.

[5] “One condition which makes [inverse carrying charges] possible is the fact that storage of [commodities] is an enterprise in which most of the costs are fixed costs, from a short-run standpoint. Another important condition is that for most of the potential suppliers of storage, the costs are joint; the owners of large storage facilities are mostly engaged either in merchandising or in processing, and maintain storage facilities largely as a necessary adjunct to their merchandising or processing business. And not only are the facilities an adjunct; the exercise of the storing function itself is a necessary adjunct to the merchandising or processing business. Consequently, the direct costs of storing over some specified period as well as the indirect costs may be charged against the associated business which remains profitable, and so also may what appear as direct losses on the storage operation itself.” (Working, 1949)

[6] Let Pt be the price in period t and let Ct be consumption during t. Consumption in any period equals stocks carried into the period plus current production minus stocks carried out of the period. Consequently consumption, ft(Ct), can be rewritten as Pt = ft(St-1 + XtSt), where St-1 is stocks at the end of period t-1, Xt is production during t and St is stocks at the end of t. In general, price in the next period minus price in the current period may be expressed as a decreasing function of stocks carried out of the current period. Symbolically the demand for storage from period t to period t+1 can be represented as Pt+1Pt = ft+1(Ct+1) – ft(Ct), which is equivalent to formula presented in article.

[7] mt(St) is the net total cost of storage and mt΄(St) is the net marginal cost of storage. Again let St denote the stocks carried out of period t. Let ot(St) be the total outlay on physical storage where ot΄>0, rt(St) the total risk-aversion factor where rt΄>0, and ct(St) the total convenience yield where ct΄≥0. The net marginal cost of storage need not be positive.

References:
Blas, Javier, “Growing demand for bullion hands banks gold opportunity in storage” Financial Times, June 12, 2010.

Brennan, M. (1958). “The Supply of Storage” American Economic Review, 47(1), pp 50-72.

Fama, Eugene F. and French, Kenneth R. (1988). “Business Cycles and the Behavior of Metals Prices” Journal of Finance, 43(5), pp 1075-1093.

Keynes, John Maynard (1930). A Treatise on Money, Volume II: The Applied Theory of Money, London: Macmillan, 1930, pp 142-147.

Kaldor, Nicholas (1939). “Speculation and Economic Stability” Review of Economic Studies, 7(1), pp 1-27.

Telser, L.G. (1958). “Futures Trading and the Storage of Cotton and Wheat” Journal of Political Economy, 66, pp 223-255.

Working, Holbrook (1948). “Theory of the Inverse Carrying Charge in Futures Markets” Journal of Farm Economics, 30(1), pp 1-28.

Working, Holbrook (1949). “The Theory of Price of Storage” American Economic Review, 39(6), December 1949, pp 1254-1262.

Tuesday, May 18, 2010

Gold Loans and Reversing a Model’s Line of Causation

Share

The 1970s was a crucial turning point in the history of 20th century gold markets. The costs of the Vietnam War and increased domestic spending had the effect of accelerating inflation. Meanwhile, US gold stock declined to $10 billion versus outstanding foreign dollar holdings estimated at about $80 billion.[1] Prior to that, the London Gold Pool made up of seven European central banks and the US Federal Reserve, a group which cooperated in maintaining the Bretton Woods System, found itself increasingly unable to balance the outflow of gold reserves and defend the fixed gold price of US$35.[2]

On August 15, 1971, President Nixon, a self-proclaimed Republican “conservative,”[3] imposed a 90-day wage and price control program and other various expansionary fiscal policies in what became known as the “Nixon Shock”[4]. Most importantly, Nixon closed the gold window to prevent foreign governments that had been holding dollar-denominated financial assets from demanding gold in exchange for their dollars. By March 1973, all of the major world currencies were floating and in November 1975, the G-7 (i.e, Group of Seven) formed to hammer out the final details on a framework for a new monetary system. That agreement, which was finalized in January 1976, called for an end to the role of gold, the establishment of SDRs as the principal reserve asset, and legitimized the de facto system of fiat currencies and floating exchange rates.

The reason for retelling this story is because these events, along with a collapse in gold prices after peaking on January 21, 1980 at the high price of $850, led directly to formation of the gold leasing market during the mid-1980s. Gold loans evolved as a means for central banks to earn a return on their bullion inventories to cover the cost of warehousing bullion[5][6] by leasing gold in exchange for a lease rate. This rate is derived from the difference between the LIBOR and Gold Forward Offered (GOFO) rate.[7] Alternatively, a central bank could swap gold in exchange for currency such as US dollars.

A leasing transaction involves a central bank transferring ownership to a leasing institution (i.e., borrower), who could then sell the gold on the spot market and invest the proceeds. At a later date, the borrower would buy back the gold and return it to the central bank while paying the lease rate. Because gold could be leased at a relatively low rate from the central bank and then sold quickly on the spot market, participants in this market included gold producers who thereby gained cash to finance gold production at a comparatively low rate of interest, while simultaneously hedging against falling gold prices.[8]

The market for gold loans developed quickly after the October 1987 stock market crash left many mining companies with reduced access to capital. Prior to 1990, GOFO rates for gold normally were below 2 percent on an annualized basis and never exceeded 3 percent, providing an inexpensive source of finance for mining companies.[9] The Financial Times reported that some 30 central banks were estimated to have engaged in gold loans around this time.[10] Then in 1990 Drexel Burnham Lambert collapsed with large outstanding gold liabilities to many central banks, resulting in increased wariness and reduced supply of gold loans from central banks.[11] As a result, lease rates rose reflecting an increased tightness in the market after the loss of central bank suppliers, as well as a substantial risk premium over the implicit cost of providing such loans.

Nevertheless, the market for gold loans grew throughout the 1990s, and an informal global interbank system developed permitting dealers to borrow gold on a short-term basis in order to fulfill delivery requirements. When bullion subsequently dropped below $300 an ounce in late 1997, and drifted in that range through 2002 in what is now referred to as the “Brown Bottom,”[12] the gold carry trade came to dominate the derivatives markets. Gold’s steady appreciation since 2002, however, has rendered this trade obsolete. As a result, there has been a wholesale transformation in the gold market since the millennium began.

In a research paper published by the Swiss Finance Institute (SFI) titled, On the Lease Rate the Convenience Yield and Speculative Effects in the Gold Futures Market, the authors examine this aspect of the gold market in detail. They note that, “…since late 2001, the profitability of the carry trade has diminished. Rising gold prices have increased risk and diminished the trade’s profitability as a result of increasing repayment costs. Consequently, the prevalence of the gold carry trade is predicated on two factors: the rate at which the central bank is willing to swap or lease gold, and whether or not the gold price is increasing.” Further, the authors Barone-Adesi, Geman and Theal (2009) observe that the COMEX “is witnessing historically low derived lease rates, decreasing hedging activity and steadily rising non-commercial open interest.”

The reason why is because the gold carry trade is risky on two dimensions. First, if the borrower invests in long-term bonds, rising interest rates could cause downward pressure on bond prices exposing the leasing institution to principal risk. Second, since the borrower is effectively short gold, if the loan is called by the central bank and gold has risen in value, they may have to purchase gold at a higher price in the spot market. Hence, there always exists the potential of driving up gold prices even higher due to short covering. This unwinding of the carry trade, as with other similar trades (e.g., yen carry trade), can result in volatile markets.

The question then is to what extent is speculation having a “tangible effect” on gold valuations, and “if so, by what mechanism does speculation influence prices?” The SFI paper points out other academics, such as Kocagil (1997), who defined “speculative intensity” as the “spread between the futures and expected spot price,” and concluded that “speculation increases spot price volatility and thus has a destabilizing effect on price.” Another researcher, Abken (1980), based his analysis on the intuition that the only return that gold yields is based on the anticipated appreciation of gold above “any marginal costs associated with the storage of gold.” Abken argues that, “during times of uncertainty, excess demand for gold as a store of value [drives] up the spot price causing stored gold to be brought to market.”

The authors of the SFI paper, on the other hand, base part of their methodology on the work of Houthakker (1957), one of the first researchers to use trader commitment data to study speculation. To understand how speculative agents can affect the gold futures market, Barone-Adesi et al. (2009) examine the open interest data from the CFTC Commitment of Traders (CoT) report, thereby identifying commercial open interest with hedging activity, and conversely, non-commercial positions with speculative activity. The authors also study the relationship between gold leasing and the level of COMEX discretionary inventory.

Not surprisingly, Barone-Adesi et al. (2009) arrive at some obvious conclusions: First, they note an ever-increasing percentage of non-commercial open interest reflects increased speculation in the gold market. Second, “the lease rate and the speculative pressure appear to work in opposition to one another; the former acts to decrease short-term bullion inventories via lease repayments, while the latter result suggests speculators dominate leasing activity in the long term… Finally, the presence of speculation in gold futures contracts can be associated with increased futures contract returns and that this effect increases with increased futures contract maturity.” What these observations suggest in their entirety is that “speculation plays a significant role in the COMEX gold futures market” as opposed to hedging activities.

Uh, okay… but isn’t this a foregone conclusion? Albeit, On the Lease Rate the Convenience Yield and Speculative Effects in the Gold Futures Market derives its determinations from some interesting theoretical ideas between the relationship of gold loans, bullion inventories, convenience yield and speculation; but in the final analysis this paper raises the specter of Muth’s (1961) Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements: “In order to explain fairly simply how expectations are formed, we advance the hypothesis that they are essentially the same as the predictions of the relevant economic theory.”

In other words, models unfortunately have the bad habit of assuming a predetermined conclusion around which expectations are formed, which in effect reverse the model’s line of causation. Our conclusion: research bias, the process where the scientists performing the research influence the results in order to portray a certain outcome, seems to be at work here—even though we happen to agree with Barone-Adesi, Geman and Theal's conclusions.

On the Lease Rate and Convenience Yield of Gold Futures

Footnotes:
[1] Spero, Joan Edelman, and Hart, Jeffrey A. (2010). The Politics of International Economic Relations. 7th ed. (originally published 1977). Boston, MA: Wadsworth Cengage Learning.

[2] Bordo, Michael D., and Barry J. Eichengreen (1993). A Retrospective on the Bretton Woods System: Lessons for International Monetary Reform. University of Chicago Press. pp. 461–494 “Chapter 9, Collapse of the Bretton Woods Fixed Rate Exchange System” by Peter M. Garber.

[3] Nixon tape conversation No. 607-11.

[4] “The Economy: Changing the World's Money” Time Magazine, Oct. 4, 1971 [First reference by Time of “Nixon Shock”]; http://www.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,905418,00.html

[5] “Bullish on Bullion” by Peter Madigan, Risk Magazine, Feb. 1, 2008, Incisive Media Ltd.

[6] According to O’Callaghan, Gary (1991), two key disadvantages in holding gold as opposed to a financial instrument are storage costs and the fact that holding gold does not bear interest.

[7] Barone-Adesi, Giovanni, Geman, Hélyette and Theal, John (2009). “On the Lease Rate, the Convenience Yield and Speculative Effects in the Gold Futures Market” (March 12, 2009). Swiss Finance Institute Research Paper No. 09-07.

[8] O’Callaghan, Gary (1991). "The Structure and Operation of the World Gold Market" International Monetary Fund, IMF Working Paper WP/91/120, Master Files Room C-525, p 33.

[9] Ibid. pp 33-34.

[10] Gooding, Kenneth, “Gold Lending Rate at Record Level,” Financial Times (London), Dec. 4, 1990, p 34.

[11] “Fool’s Gold,” The Economist, Mar. 17, 1990, p 79.

[12] Term used to describe the period between 1999 and 2002, named from the decision of Gordon Brown, then the UK's Chancellor of the Exchequer to sell half of the UK's gold reserves in a series of auctions.

References:
Barone-Adesi, Giovanni, Geman, Hélyette and Theal, John (2009). “On the Lease Rate, the Convenience Yield and Speculative Effects in the Gold Futures Market” (March 12, 2009). Swiss Finance Institute Research Paper No. 09-07.

Bordo, Michael D., and Barry J. Eichengreen (1993). A Retrospective on the Bretton Woods System: Lessons for International Monetary Reform. University of Chicago Press. pp. 461–494 “Chapter 9, Collapse of the Bretton Woods Fixed Rate Exchange System” by Peter M. Garber.

O’Callaghan, Gary (1991). “The Structure and Operation of the World Gold Market” International Monetary Fund, IMF Working Paper WP/91/120, Master Files Room C-525

Spero, Joan Edelman, and Hart, Jeffrey A. (2010). The Politics of International Economic Relations. 7th ed. (originally published 1977). Boston, MA: Wadsworth Cengage Learning.

Saturday, May 1, 2010

Prisoners Dilemma on the Paradox of Solution

Share
Of all the inhabitants of the inferno, none but Lucifer knows that hell is hell, and the secret function of purgatory is to make of heaven an effective reality. ~Arnold Bennett, English novelist (1867 – 1931)

Martin A. Armstrong is a man who is spending time in purgatory—both literally and figuratively. For those not aware, Armstrong is the former chairman of Princeton Economics International Ltd. indicted in 1999 on charges of bilking Japanese investors. He languished seven years in jail for contempt of court, supposedly the longest someone has ever been held without trial in United States history. All the while, Armstrong claimed that he was innocent of the fraud itself before finally pleading guilty in 2007. He is now serving a five-year sentence for conspiracy to commit fraud.[1][2]

Said to be “bizarrre (sic) and eccentric,” this “notorious… self-professed expert in the history of money and things gold”[3] is also a prolific writer whose narrative is the kind of grist for the mill influencing Matt Taibbi’s “investigative journalism”.[4] It is therefore not surprising, given Armstrong’s incarceration and his self-claimed title as “America’s #1 Political Prisoner,” to discover that his writings are tinged with conspiracy theories. On the other hand, as Kissinger once noted, “Even a paranoid can have enemies.”[5] Regardless you are probably asking, why devote time discussing The Paradox of Solution if Armstrong’s credibility is questionable? [Article continues below embedded paper.]

The Paradox of Solution 4-18-10


To begin with, notwithstanding the background context it’s a short and interesting read, and for someone who you would expect to “rail against the machine” it comes as a surprise to learn that Armstrong defends the establishment. Well, at least in regards to the “original intent” of the Federal Reserve and his implied support for the Volker rule. On this and the U.S. Government’s evolving policy response to the financial crisis, Armstrong reveals himself to be a man seemingly caught between faith and skepticism. His voice predictably adds to the chorus of doomsayers, but then he lends ineffectual advice as to how we can avoid our fate.

Second, while some may argue that Armstrong suffers from the Dunning–Kruger effect, the literary tradition of the wise fool who “speakest but sad truths”[6] provides reason enough to read The Paradox of Solution. As William S. Burroughs’ once said, “Sometimes paranoia’s just having all the facts.” And where Armstrong’s essay becomes truly fascinating is in our humble opinion the last third of the article where he begins to discuss that “meaningless and intangible social construct,”[7] money.
When money was tangible, debasement was the game. Hence, I’m sorry, but a GOLD & SILVER STANDARD will not eliminate inflation! Those who argue for “sound money” just do not understand that what is money, is far less important than WHO controls money. Politicians from ancient times have always sought to make just a little bit more to cover their spending that has never been responsible. Some have needed money desperately to defend the nation as was the case in Athens. Others just wanted to spend more to have nice things like Nero. Regardless of the reason, it is WHO controls the quantity and quality of money that truly matters—NOT what is actually money!
There is a video on the Intertubes[8] featuring a “steel cage death match” on the subject of “inflation versus deflation” between James Grant, founder of the venerable Grant's Interest Rate Observer, and the well-respected David Rosenberg, chief economist with Canada’s Gluskin Sheff & Associates [see: http://tinyurl.com/2dbgcvb]. Say what you will about Armstrong, but in both this debate and a March 31, 2010 Bloomberg interview with Keith McCullough, James Grant had the nerve to ask a most important matter of faith, ‘what is the US dollar?’
But maybe that’s the trouble with Treasuries. The fundamental trouble is that they are IOUs denominated in a currency that nobody knows what it is. What’s a dollar? What’s a dollar? David can’t tell me. Nobody can tell me. If Alexander Hamilton were here, and unbriefed (sic) on the events of the past two hundred years, he could tell me. And what he would say is that the dollar is defined as 371 and ¼ grains of pure silver, or 24 and ¾ grains of pure gold. And it was too under the 1792 Coinage Act which Hamilton himself wrote. And those were the definitions, and incidentally, Section 19 of that landmark monetary legislation ends in these telling words, quote “shall suffer death” closed quote. Now, can you tell me what kind of felony was punishable by death under an Act to regulate the mint? The act of debasing the currency was—that was a capital offense. So watch your back Ben Bernanke [audience laughter], cycles turn. [Time: 8’50”]
Nevertheless, “cash is king,” especially in a liquidity crisis; however, for cash to function as a means to discharge debt, then the largely unasked question is: what defines cash as cash?[9] Such philosophical musings may seem from the realm of madmen or fools, but when the highly respected James Grant half-jokingly references the following satirical article by The Onion, U.S. Economy Grinds to Halt As Nation Realizes Money Just A Symbolic, Mutually Shared Illusion,[10] you know that something is amiss. But what exactly?

Armstrong, alluding to a collective fear of what the future holds for “Western dominance,” strikes at the very heart of the matter. In hunter-gather societies, “there is no TRADE because there is no concept of the future as we understand it… In order for society to have created a concept of money, there had to have been the realization that there is a tomorrow. Something of VALUE is now to be stored and retained… Once this concept of future was born yielding the idea of VALUE, everything from banking to derivatives began to emerge even in ancient times… The concept of barter thus emerged with the concept of future. Then, money emerged as a universal language of barter… The wealth of a nation emerged from the productive forces of its people.”

According to Ludwig von Mises, “The concept of money as a creature of law and the state is clearly untenable. It is not justified by a single phenomenon of the market. To ascribe to the state the power of dictating the laws of exchange, is to ignore the fundamental principles of money-using society.”[11] Armstrong echoes this sentiment, “It is nice to create a unrealistic view of a world where all we have to do is restore a gold standard and all will be well.” But then he turns around and disagrees with Mises, “It is not what is money, but who controls it that has always counted.”

Armstrong seems to view the world as a top-down establishmentarian exercise by a political class, which in turn he rails against. But with respect to the “control” of money, it has not always been true that this was the function of government. Alessandri and Haldane (2009), who reference Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) in their paper Banking on the State, clarify monetary history for us: “From the earliest times, the relationship between banks and the state was often rocky. Sovereign default on loans was an everyday hazard for the banks, especially among states vanquished in war. Indeed, through the ages sovereign default has been the single biggest cause of banking collapse.”

John Locke once wrote, “Credit is nothing but the expectation of money, within some limited time.”[12] As Grant (1994) noted, “To credit is to believe and to lend money it is necessary to trust someone.” Yet, financial history is rife with periods when “prolonged prosperity wore down the skepticism of creditors” only to result in eras of economic hardships.[13] It seems that we have entered into such a period with Chinese officials and some leading economists wanting a greater role for Special Drawing Rights (SDRs) in foreign exchange reserves. Yet, as Aiyar (2009) noted in his paper, An International Monetary Fund Currency to Rival the Dollar? “…the SDR is not a currency in its own right. Rather, it is a derivative of four national currencies. A derivative is not a currency.”

Armstrong, to be fair, taps into the current zeitgeist of confusion regarding the Frankenstein nature of our financial system. As Selgin (2010), senior fellow at the Cato Institute, affirmed: “the Jekyll and Hyde nature of contemporary central banks… has made apparent our utter dependence on such banks as instruments for assuring the continuous flow of credit in the aftermath of a financial bust and the same institutions’ capacity to fuel the financial booms that make severe busts possible in the first place.” In that one line Selgin actually does a better job in describing Armstrong’s so-called “paradox of solution”.

In the final analysis, however, Armstrong’s ramblings are indeed perplexing. He is anti-Washington, anti-SEC, and anti-CFTC, but at the same time he wants to “regulate the REPO market to eliminate posting collateral that explodes in the middle of the night.” Is this to be done by a neutered Federal Reserve? According to Armstrong who positions himself as a Fed apologist, “The Fed is incapable to [interest rate] management and should just raise or lower the reserve ratio banks must put up at the Fed.” As the saying goes, with friends like these who needs enemies.

Maybe Armstrong is just economic literature’s “wise fool” reincarnate into real life. Albeit, the world is now a place in which Joseph Stiglitz, the Nobel Prize-winning economist and Columbia University professor, speaks against the orthodoxy of “rational expectations” asserting that economists are among those at fault for the financial crisis, which exposed “major flaws” in prevailing ideas.[14] Wise fool or not, Armstrong comes across as a man who seeks redemption by trying to save us from ourselves. Then again, the same could be said about Fed Chairman, Ben Bernanke. Perhaps Sir Walter Scott put it best in his novel, Ivanhoe: “Our heads are in the lion's mouth,” said Wamba, in a whisper to Gurth, “get them out how we can.”[15]

Footnotes:
[1] Martin A. Armstrong. (2010, April 9). In Wikipedia, Free Encyclopedia. Retrieved: May 1, 2010, from http://tinyurl.com/2847kvo.

[2] “Japanese Regulators Get a 2d 'Scalp' Under Their Belts.” Stephanie Strom, New York Times, September 17, 1999. http://tinyurl.com/2edlqwk

[3] “The Enigma of Martin Armstrong.” January 04, 2009. http://tinyurl.com/2595sb4

[4] “What Is Ture/Slant?” Matt Taibbi, Taibblog http://trueslant.com/matttaibbi/

[5] Source: “His Legacy: Realism and Allure.” Time.com, Jan. 24, 1977. http://tinyurl.com/2d8smj4.

[6] Scott, W., Sir, 1771-1832. Ivanhoe, by Sir Walter Scott. 39015036703273. Edinburgh, A. & C. Black.

[7] “U.S. Economy Grinds to Halt As Nation Realizes Money Just a Symbolic, Mutually Shared Illusion.” The Onion, Inc., Issue 46-07, February 16, 2010. http://tinyurl.com/ycy9bct

[8] Etymology: chiefly Internet slang, humorous, from the “Series of tubes” analogy used on June 28, 2006 by then United States Senator Ted Stevens to describe the Internet.

[9] Frankfurter, Michael “Mack” (2010). “The Mysterious Case of Hamilton’s Monetary Enterprise, the Financial Instability Hypothesis, and Exter’s Inverted Pyramid.” Draft Article, February 15, 2010. http://docstoc.com/docs/25405145

[10] “U.S. Economy Grinds to Halt As Nation Realizes Money Just a Symbolic, Mutually Shared Illusion.” The Onion, Inc., Issue 46-07, February 16, 2010.

[11] Von Mises, Ludwig and Greaves, Percy L. (1978). “On the Manipulation of Money and Credit.” Dobbs Ferry, N.Y.: Free Market Books, p. 69.

[12] Source: “Pleas for peace and union against political intolerance and sectional animosity: Speeches of Thomas F. Bayard, R. E. Withers, S. B. Maxey in the Senate of the United States, March 30, 1876, with the speech of George S. Boutwell.” Harvard University, 1876. Digital Copy, p. 74. “Speech of Hon. Thomas Francis Bayard, of Delaware, in the United States Senate, May 27, 1878.”

[13] Grant, James (1994). “Money of the mind: Borrowing and lending in America from the Civil War to Michael Milken.” New York: Noonday Press, pp. 5 & 8.

[14] “Stiglitz Says Crisis Exposed ‘Major Flaws’ in Economic Ideas.” Scott Lanman, BusinessWeek, January 2, 2010.

[15] Scott, W., Sir, 1771-1832. Ivanhoe, by Sir Walter Scott. 39015036703273. Edinburgh, A. & C. Black.

References:
Aiyar, Swaminathan S. (2009). “An International Monetary Fund Currency to Rival the Dollar?” The Cato Institute, Center for Global Liberty & Prosperity, Development Policy Analysis, No. 10, July 7, 2009.

Frankfurter, Michael “Mack” (2010). “The Mysterious Case of Hamilton’s Monetary Enterprise, the Financial Instability Hypothesis, and Exter’s Inverted Pyramid.” Docstoc, Draft Article, February 15, 2010. http://docstoc.com/docs/25405145

Grant, James (1994). “Money of the mind: Borrowing and lending in America from the Civil War to Michael Milken.” New York: Noonday Press.

Von Mises, Ludwig and Greaves, Percy L. (1978). “On the Manipulation of Money and Credit.” Dobbs Ferry, N.Y.: Free Market Books.

Haldane, Andrew G. and Alessandri, Piergiorgio (2009). “Banking on the State.” Bank of England. Based on a presentation delivered at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago twelfth annual International Banking Conference on “The International Financial Crisis: Have the Rules of Finance Changed?” 25 September 2009.

Reinhart, C. M and Rogoff, K (2009). “This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of
Financial Folly.” Princeton University Press.

Selgin, George (2010). “Central Banks as Sources of Financial Instability.” The Cato Institute, The Independent Review, V. 14, N. 4, Spring 2010, pp. 485-496.

Thursday, April 15, 2010

Managed Futures: Is It an Asset Class?

Share
For those unfamiliar with the term managed futures, it is a niche sector of alternative investments that evolved out of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission Act of 1974, and refers to professionally managed assets in the commodity and financial futures markets. Management is facilitated by either Commodity Trading Advisors (CTAs) or Commodity Pool Operators (CPOs) who are regulated by the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) and the National Futures Association (NFA).

Managed futures is the little kid brother to the hedge fund juggernaut. Even so, its impact upon the industry is writ large in two significant and related ways: first, managed futures unlike its brethren hedge funds operate in a highly regulated environment; second, this same regulated environment which imposes disclosure and reporting requirements lends itself to fomenting lower barriers of entry for new talent to evolve. Interestingly, the institutionalization of alternative investments can be traced back to the development of managed futures performance tracking databases first established around 1979. This data became the basis for an academic body of research on managed futures beginning with the seminal study by Harvard Business School professor, Dr. John E. Lintner.

So is managed futures an asset class? Let’s cut to the chase… in this writer’s humble opinion the answer is no, absolutely not. Well, maybe we would reconsider if managed futures was confined to just commodity interests, but with futures contracts also trading on financials, managed futures is as much an asset class as are registered investment advisers, mutual funds or hedge funds.

Lee, Malek, Nash and Rose (2006), on the other hand, would beg to differ. Their paper The Beta of Managed Futures makes the case that the predominant strategy in this space is trend following, and thus an appropriate benchmark for managed futures is one that mechanically mimics trend following systems. To say the least, it’s an interesting approach, and one which addresses issues related to peer group analysis and indices based on a composite of individual CTA programs. As Lee, Malek, Nash and Rose posit, “CTA indices represent the result of investing in CTAs, not the results of investing like CTAs.”

The weak part of their thesis, however, has to do with the assumption that managed futures essentially represents just trend following strategies. Lee, Malek, Nash and Rose readily admit that CTAs “employ a wide range of methods” and that such methods are “by no means exhaustive,” and include “breakout systems, systems based on moving averages and systems based on pattern recognition”. They attempt to reconcile this issue by creating a “beta benchmark” that “consists of twenty systems trading the world’s most liquid… markets”. According to their study, they found that their benchmark, for the period analyzed, was highly correlated to large CTAs.

That said, a mechanical trading index approach still leaves questions, including the validity of the trading methods utilized and the robustness of the parameters used to supposedly define the “beta of managed futures”. At a more subtle level, questions are raised by a relatively new concept proposed by Lo (2004) called the Adaptive Markets Hypothesis (AMH). AMH is based on an evolutionary approach to economic interactions and builds on the research of Wilson (1975), Lo (1999) and Farmer (2002) in applying the principles of competition, reproduction and natural selection.

In light of AMH, the paper by Lawrence Harris, The Winners and Losers of the Zero-Sum Game: The Origins of Trading Profits, Price Efficiency and Market Liquidity provides an intellectually honest answer as to the true dynamics underlying managed futures.

The following is from the paper’s abstract; written in 1993, it is not something you’d likely see in an academic paper nowadays: “Trading is a zero-sum game when measured relative to underlying fundamental values. No trader can profit without another trader losing. People trade because they obtain external benefits from trading… Three groups of stylized characteristic traders are examined. Winning traders trade for profit. Utilitarian traders trade because their external benefits of trading are greater than their losses. Futile traders expect to profit but for a variety of reasons their expectation are not realized.”

Harris goes on to discuss the obvious but little acknowledged fact that, “Trading performance reflects a combination of skill and luck. Successful traders may be skilled traders or simply lucky unskilled traders. Likewise, unsuccessful traders may be unskilled traders or unlucky skilled traders... We would like to believe that skill accounts for most variation in past performance among traders and managers,” but “from past performance alone, you cannot confidently determine who is skilled and who is lucky.” Therein lies the conundrum and the alternative investment industry's dirty little secret.

From this 20,000 foot level, the paper drills down and “examines the economics that determine who wins and who loses when trading.” Harris considers “the styles of value-motivated traders, inside informed traders, headline traders, event study traders, dealers, market-makers, specialists, scalpers, day traders, upstairs position traders, block facilitators, market data monitors, electronic proprietary traders, quote-matchers, front-runners, technical traders, chartists, momentum traders, contrarians, pure arbitrageurs, statistical arbitrageurs, pairs traders, risk arbitrageurs, bluffers, ‘pure’ traders, noise traders, hedgers, uninformed investors, indexers, pseudo-informed traders, fledglings and gamblers.” The paper goes on to “describe each of these traders, explain how their trading generates profits or losses, and consider how they affect price efficiency and liquidity.”

Because this paper was written in the early 1990s some of the descriptions may admittedly be dated relative to technological and quantitative developments in the field of trading since. Nevertheless, Winner and Losers of the Zero-Sum Game is a little noticed gem of a working paper whose astute observations ring true even today despite the escalating arms race in academic working papers being spun out of the university-industry revolving door.

Then why is managed futures constantly referred to as an asset class? Answer: out of laziness. However, such laziness goes beyond just the financial industry’s responsibility; truth is, half the problem lies with investors themselves—try as one might to delineate sophisticated investment concepts, the most common reaction is investors’ eyes glazing over.

So if managed futures is not an asset class, then what is it? As with many of the acronyms and lingo that the financial industry regularly comes up with, mainly for marketing reasons, the term has become a misnomer. What started out as an investment activity that was defined by regulations is now conventionally considered by many an asset class. C'est la vie

Winners and Losers of the Zero-Sum Game - Harris

References:
Harris, Lawrence. “The Winners and Losers of the Zero-Sum Game: The Origins of Trading Profits, Price Efficiency and Market Liquidity” School of Business Administration, University of Southern California, Draft 0.911, May 7, 1993.

Lee, Timothy C.; Malek, Marc H.; Nash, Jeffrey T.; and Rose, Jeffrey M. “The Beta of Managed Futures,” Conquest Capital Group LLC, February 2006.

Lintner, John E. “The Potential Role of Managed Commodity—Financial Futures Accounts (and/or Funds) in Portfolios of Stocks and Bonds” Presented at the Annual Conference of the Financial Analysts Federation, May 1983.

Lo, Andrew W. “The Adaptive Markets Hypothesis; Market efficiency from an evolutionary perspective” The Journal of Portfolio Management, 30th Anniversary Issue 2004, pp. 15-29.

Wednesday, April 7, 2010

Using a Zero-Beta Asset for Measuring Variance

Share
Numerous research papers on gold begin by establishing that of all the commodities gold is a distinct asset. Anecdotal themes include the idea that human civilization has long been enamored with gold going back to ancient times, as well as the fact that, unlike most other commodities, bullion can be stored almost indefinitely and requires very little maintenance. These attributes are given as the reason gold has throughout history been used as a medium of exchange and maintains its purchasing power. In Research Study No. 22, Gold as a Store of Value, published by the World Gold Council in 1998, author Stephen Harmston relates the oft-heard story that "an ounce of gold bought 350 loaves of bread in the time of Nebuchadnezzar… still buys approximately 350 loaves of bread today." Notwithstanding that we have been unable to identify an archeological or biblical source for this tale,[1] let us assume that this bit of trivia is true, along with other stories involving an ounce of gold buying a nice suit, armor or otherwise.

Assuming gold does have the unique ability to maintain consistent purchasing power over an extended period of time, such asset would seem to fit the definition of a zero-beta asset. This is the conclusion of a paper by McCown and Zimmerman (2006) titled, Is Gold a Zero-Beta Asset? Analysis of the Investment Potential of Precious Metals in which they analyze gold returns using three different frameworks: the Sharp (1964) and Lintner (1965) capital asset pricing model (CAPM); the arbitrage pricing theory (APT) of Ross (1976); and cointegration using a test methodology developed by Elliott, Rothenberg and Stock (1996), and another methodology by Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt and Shin (1992).

Running a regression analysis from 1970 to 2003 where the "risk-free" rate is the yield on the US T-Bill, McCown and Zimmerman use three different proxies for the market portfolio: MSCI US Index, MSCI World denominated in local currency, and MSCI World denominated in US dollar. Acknowledging that the CAPM is "limited in usefulness as a tool for investment analysis," the authors observe that "all of the estimated beta coefficients for gold are statistically indifferent from zero," and therefore gold does not reflect "much, if any, systematic risk". In their CAPM study the conclusion is that gold effectively behaves as a zero-beta asset, yet it also "has a positive risk premium". The APT methodology and cointegration tests also validate the authors' hypothesis.

The paper concludes that gold shows "the characteristics of zero-beta asset," and that the "mean return is just slightly higher than that of T-Bills". Further, "estimates of CAPM and the APT show that both gold and silver bear virtually no market risk, and their estimated betas are statistically indifferent from zero". All three frameworks showed evidence of inflation-hedging ability when added to an investor’s portfolio. Obviously, McCown and Zimmerman's research doesn’t take into account the rise of gold since 2003, which brings up that "old saw" about how correlation does not imply causation. Given that gold is priced today much higher than in 2003, yet inflation has generally been tame since the millennium, raises a question concerning the underlying perspective of this study. Perhaps a better framework for studying gold is that is acts like a currency proxy?

Over the course of our lifetime we are trained to value assets from a US dollar-centric perspective, and it is hard for US-based investors to think differently. In Europe one views prices from a euro-centric perspective. However, it is also possible to revalue the economy and markets from the perspective of preserving purchasing power. When assets such as stocks are revalued in gold as a unit of account, we gain a completely different outlook on whether or not such assets have risen or fallen, and to what extent. For example, if we were to value the Dow Jones Industrial Average, not in US dollars but in ounces of gold, it would have cost around 30 ounces of gold to buy the Average at 10,000 when the index first crossed over that line in 1998. When it crossed over that line again back in October 2009, it would have cost less than 10 ounces of gold.

In a March 30, 2010 Financial Times article titled, "Will negative swap spreads be our coal mine canaries?" Gillian Tett forces us to rethink what constitutes a "risk-free" rate. In finance classes the rate based on the three-month US T-Bill is almost always assumed as the risk-free proxy for input into the CAPM. But what if, as Tett suggests in her article, that there is no risk-free rate? Black's (1972) zero-beta CAPM provides a solution by supposing a riskless asset does not exist, and that investors hold different risky portfolios all existing on the efficent frontier. In order to calculate the zero-beta CAPM, one simply replaces the "risk-free" rate with a "zero-beta" rate. This is necessary to calculate the mean-variance of the market portfolio.[2]

One of the more interesting aspects of McCown and Zimmerman's research was that gold still reflected characteristics of a "zero-beta" asset when using the 'MSCI World denominated in local currency' as a proxy for the market portfolio. When employing the CAPM, analysts traditionally measure portfolio variance denominated in either the US dollar or in the local currency in which the portfolio's assets are actually denominated. What we are suggesting is that zero-beta also implies the idea of relative valuation when measuring variance based on some unit of account. In other words, a better method for measuring variance when using the zero-beta CAPM necessitates an exchange rate constant which consistently maintains purchasing power over an extremely long time horizon, rather than a floating exchange rate variable which reflexively alters the value of the assets it is suppose to measure.

Footnotes:
[1] Dr. Claude Mariottini, Professor of Old Testament, Northern Baptist Seminary, states that no where in the Old Testament does it say that "in the days of Nebuchadnezzar an ounce of gold bought 350 loaves of bread." Further, Dr. Mariottini logically points out that "one must assume that the ounce, a unit of weight in the avoirdupois system, once used in the United Kingdom and still used in the United States, was also used in Babylon. Since the Babylonians did not use imperial units, this statement is false." Source: Gold and Bread http://tinyurl.com/yjxpn6d

[2] Zhang, Lu. "The Capital Asset Pricing Model" Stephen M. Ross School of Business, University of Michigan (2007).

Is Gold a Zero-Beta Asset? Investment Potential of Precious Metals

References:
Harmston, Stephen. "Gold as a Store of Value" Research Study No. 22, World Gold Council (November 1998).

Mariottini, Claude. "Gold and Bread" http://doctor.claudemariottini.com/ (June 10, 2008).

McCown, James Ross and Zimmerman, John R. "Is Gold a Zero-Beta Asset? Analysis of the Investment Potential of Precious Metals" Meinders School of business, Oklahoma City University (July 24, 2006).

Tett, Gillian. "Will negative swap spreads be our coal mine canaries?" Financial Times (March 30 2010).

Zhang, Lu. "The Capital Asset Pricing Model" Stephen M. Ross School of Business, University of Michigan (2007).

Saturday, March 20, 2010

Alpha-Beta and the Heisenberg Uncertainty Principle

Share
In physics, complementarity is a basic principle of quantum theory closely identified with the Copenhagen interpretation, and refers to effects such as "wave–particle duality," in which different measurements made on a system reveal it to have either particle-like or wave-like properties. Niels Bohr is usually associated with this concept, which he developed at Copenhagen with Heisenberg as a philosophical adjunct to the mathematics of quantum mechanics and in particular the Heisenberg uncertainty principle. The Heisenberg uncertainty principle states that certain pairs of physical properties, like position and momentum, cannot both be known with precision. That is, the more precisely one property is known, the less precisely the other property can be known.

In Chinese philosophy, the concept of "yīn yang" is used to describe how polar or seemingly contrary forces are interconnected and interdependent in the natural world, and how they give rise to each other in turn. Yin yang are complementary opposites within a greater whole. Everything has both yin and yang aspects, although yin or yang elements may manifest more strongly in different objects or at different times. Yin yang constantly interacts, never existing in absolute stasis as symbolized by the Taijitu symbol.

A similar paradox exists within the CAPM paradigm involving the relationship between the concept of "beta," as determined by the market portfolio, and "alpha," which loosely represents "a proxy for manager skill". As is inferred by our prior posting, "The CAPM Debate and the Search for 'True Beta'", the yin yang "whole" relates to the "True Beta" concept which Jagannathan and Wang (1996) theorized must encompass "the aggregate wealth portfolio of all agents in the economy". Moreover, one could apply aspects of "beta" to the symbology associated with "yin," which is usually characterized as slow, diffuse, tranquil, femininity and night; and apply aspects of "alpha" to the symbolism of "yang," which by contrast is characterized as fast, hard, focused, masculinity and day.

Schneeweis (1999) investigates this alpha-beta paradox in his article, "Alpha, Alpha, Whose got the Alpha?" wherein he writes about the problem of measuring "alpha" by raising the question of "how to define the expected risk of the manager’s investment position". In other words, when marketing "alpha" portfolio managers often assume "the reference benchmark is the appropriate benchmark and that the strategy has the same leverage as the benchmark". Unfortunately, "[w]ith the exception of a strategy that is designed to replicate the returns of the benchmark, the alpha generated by this approach is essentially meaningless". Hence, investors often mistakenly rely on a single-index model as a meaningful benchmark from which to gauge the factors "driving the return of the strategy," when often a "multi-factor model should be used to describe the various market factors that drive the return strategy". The problem is that statistically it is "better to over-specify a model… than to under-specify. If the model is over-specified, many of the betas will simply be zero. However, if under-specified, there is the possibility of significant bias".

Which brings us back to the Heisenberg uncertainty principle...

Just like the physical properties of position and momentum cannot both be known with precision, the properties of "alpha" and "beta" also cannot be measured precisely. This statement can be interpreted in two different ways: According to Heisenberg its meaning is that it is impossible to determine simultaneously both properties with any great degree of accuracy or certainty. However, according to Ballentine and others this is not a statement about the limitations of a researcher's ability to measure particular quantities of a system, but it is a statement about the nature of the system itself as described by the equations.


Alpha Alpha Whose Got the Alpha - Schneeweis

References:
Ballentine, L.E. The statistical interpretation of quantum mechanics, Rev. Mod. Phys. 42, 358–381 (1970).

Bohr, Niels. "Atomic Physics and Human Knowledge," p. 38.

Heisenberg, W. "Über den anschaulichen Inhalt der quantentheoretischen Kinematik und Mechanik," In: Zeitschrift für Physik. 43 1927, S. 172–198.

Jagannathan, Ravi; McGrattan, Ellen R. (1995). "The CAPM Debate" Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Vol. 19, No. 4, Fall 1995, pp. 2-17.

Jagannathan, Ravi; Wang, Zhenyu (1993). "The CAPM is Alive and Well" Research Department Staff Report 165. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

Jagannathan, Ravi; Wang, Zhenyu (1996). "The Conditional CAPM and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns" Journal of Finance, Vol. 51, No. 1, March, pp. 3-53.

Schneeweis, Thomas (1999). "Alpha, Alpha, Whose got the Alpha?" University of Massachusetts, School of Management (October 5, 1999).

Monday, March 15, 2010

The CAPM Debate and the Search for "True Beta"

Share
Conventional investment theory states that when an investor constructs a well-diversified portfolio, the unsystematic sources of risk are diversified away leaving the systematic or non-diversifiable source of risk as the relevant risks. The capital asset pricing model (CAPM), developed by Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965) and Black (1972) [zero-beta version], asserts that the correct measure of this riskiness is its measure known as the "beta coefficient" or just "beta". Effectively, beta is a measure of an asset’s correlated volatility relative to the volatility of the overall market. Consequently, given the beta of an asset and the risk-free rate, the CAPM should be able to predict the expected return for that asset, and correspondingly the expected risk premium as well.

This explanation is textbook. However, unbeknownst to most investors, there has been a long running argument in academic circles on the CAPM and other pricing models, even within the milieu of traditional investments. Without going into the details of this debate, certain empirical studies have revealed "cross-sectional variations" in the CAPM questioning the validity of the model. In direct response to the challenge by Fama and French (1992), Jagannathan and Wang (1996) theorized that “…the lack of empirical support for the CAPM may be due to the inappropriateness of some assumptions made to facilitate the empirical analysis of the model. Such an analysis must include a measure of the return on the aggregate wealth portfolio of all agents in the economy.”

Financial institutions have not been left behind by these evolving academic theories. Index creation and benchmarking has become standard fare, and since the introduction of 'exchange traded funds' (ETFs), a veritable industry has developed around the "multiple beta" concept. But by no means has the plethora of these instruments captured every aspect of the aggregate wealth portfolio of all agents in the global economy, although at the current pace of ETF development it would seem that this is the undeclared objective.

Such backdrop is the principal context which gives impetus to the notion of "exotic betas". The term, a recent addition to the investment lexicon which evolved from ideas advanced by proponents of alternative investments, suggests that certain alternative investment assets and/or strategies, representing commonly pursued market paradigms, can be identified, tracked and replicated employing a predefined passive approach/model similar to traditional index construction.

This leaves open the question as to whether institutions, through sophisticated financial engineering, can truly capture in a passive way all possible sources of return in the global economy. Or, does some aspect which the industry loosely calls alpha (i.e., skill-based returns) always remain outside the grasp of such institutions’ arbitrary models of beta?

Jagannathan - The CAPM Debate

References:
Black, Fischer (1972). “Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing” Journal of Business 45, July, pp. 444-455.

Fama, Eugene F.; French, Kenneth R. (1992). “The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns” Journal of Finance 47, June, pp. 427-465.

Jagannathan, Ravi; McGrattan, Ellen R. (1995). “The CAPM Debate” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Vol. 19, No. 4, Fall 1995, pp. 2-17

Jagannathan, Ravi; Wang, Zhenyu (1993). “The CAPM is Alive and Well” Research Department Staff Report 165. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

Jagannathan, Ravi; Wang, Zhenyu (1996). “The Conditional CAPM and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns” Journal of Finance, Vol. 51, No. 1, March, pp. 3-53.

Sunday, March 7, 2010

The Mysterious Case of an Enigma within a Paradox

Share
In 1995, Cambridge University Press published in its Journal of Economic History an article by John R. Garrett titled, "Monetary Policy and Expectations: Market-Control Techniques and the Bank of England, 1925-1931". Garrett begins by referencing Richard Sayers who, as the official Bank of England historian with full access to confidential archives, revealed in a 1976 book titled, "The Bank of England 1891-1944," that the Bank had influenced interest rates by manipulating reported gold flows between 1925-1931. Based on such enigmatic evidence, Garrett (1995) "models expectations manipulation as a monetary policy channel," and shows that "gold flow falsification was over two-thirds as effective as an open-market operation."

As Garrett noted, "These results contradict accepted new classical models and suggest that credibility benefits from new classical policy are small." The enigma within a paradox relates to the concept of 'rational expectations' as described below:

Our working paper investigated various models which deal with the potential sources of return to speculators in the futures market, including one of our own which exemplifies the complexity of these markets. Admittedly, models are only an abstraction from reality. Expecting such models to be exactly right is unreasonable, and it is generally understood that neoclassical economic theory has inherent limitations related to the analysis of markets within the context of “rational equilibrium systems.” Such systems are based on perfect competition, and assume markets naturally return to equilibrium after a disturbance. Hence, modern finance seeks to maximize utility and/or profits in a world of constraints based on the choices of “rational” economic agents. By definition then, these models relegate speculators to the role of that very agent which maintains equilibrium. Yet a survey of real-life speculators reveals that these practitioners do not as a general rule use academic models in their day-to-day trading decisions. Paradoxically, this same group plays a key influence upon the selfsame futures data from which such models are constructed. So if the data series is assumed to represent equilibrium and “the future is merely the statistical reflection of the past,” then one could inversely argue that perfect competition and rational expectations minimize these models’ usefulness as a mechanism from which to make speculative decisions. In other words, rational expectations compel such models to simply validate that current price data is equal to equilibrium, unless the opposite is true—that markets are in fact imperfect and rational expectations is untenable, which in turn undermines the veracity of these models. [Source: The Search for the Beta of Commodity Futures]
Following the twists and turns in this "riddle, wrapped in a mystery, inside an enigma" is the implication that the 'rational expectations equilibrium' paradox is being turned back on itself by the central banks themselves. It is not just that central banks are using game theory to manage expectations (and by implication models based on rational expectations), the 1925-1931 Bank of England episode illustrates a situation where economic reality was changed by a central bank despite it being based on a lie. In Garret's words:

Markets can not tell when a central bank is lying. They then have the option to accept all or reject all forecast information emanating from the central bank. Under such circumstances the credibility model asserts that private financial markets reject all central bank information. This is possible because the financial markets' private information is assumed to be almost com- plete. However, the results presented here contradict this assumption and lend support to the opposite case: the markets' private information is so incomplete that they can not dispense with central-bank sources. The implication for the credibility model is devastating because perva- sive ignorance and uncertainty allow the central bank to maintain its position as a disseminator of forecast information even if the central bank is guilty of extreme dishonesty, as under Norman. Under these circumstances monetary policy will be an effective instrument to stabilize the economy against both money demand and real shocks, which contradicts the core result found in the large and influential credibility-model literature.
The article "Priceless: How The Federal Reserve Bought The Economics Profession" adds support to this idea of an enigma within a paradox, and lends credibility to concerns of economic/market groupthink. In the words of Morpheus: "I imagine that right now, you're feeling a bit like Alice. Hmm? Tumbling down the rabbit hole?"

John Garrett - Monetary Policy and Expectations

References:
Garrett, John R. (1995) "Monetary Policy and Expectations: Market-Control Techniques and the Bank of England, 1925-1931" The Journal of Economic History, Cambridge University Press, Sept. 1995, pp. 612-636

Frankfurter, Mack and Accomazzo, Davide (2007) "Is Managed Futures an Asset Class? The Search for the Beta of Commodity Futures" (December 31, 2007). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1029243